What’s the deal?

About the Author: Nick Phipps

16 November 2018

Alasdair Smith is an Emeritus Professor of Economics at the University of Sussex and is a member of the UK Trade Policy Observatory.

The UK Cabinet has signed off the draft EU Withdrawal Agreement (WA) and the Political Declaration (PD) about the future UK-EU trade relationship. The WA has had such a rocky reception in the Conservative Party that the future path of decision-making is a bit uncertain, but it is likely that these documents will also be agreed by the EU summit later this month. The decision-making then passes one way or another to the UK Parliament. Politics has dominated this week’s debates, but decisions need to be informed by economic assessment. Let’s consider the economic costs and benefits of the choices which Parliament will have to make.

The first option is No Deal: Parliament rejects the Prime Minister’s proposal and no alternative proposal commands a majority.

Unless Parliament makes a positive decision to choose another course, the default option is that the UK will leave the EU on 29 March 2019, without a WA. In the short run, this would cause considerable economic disruption. Airlines might be grounded, supplies of pharmaceuticals and nuclear fuel could be disrupted, and long delays in the time-critical supply chains across the Dover Straits would cause shortages of fruit and vegetables and other goods on the shelves of UK supermarkets. It’s hard to predict how long the short-term disruption would continue, and hard to quantify the economic costs with more precision than “huge”. Some big costs would be long-lasting: customs delays at borders, regulatory obstacles and tariff barriers affecting both the just-in-time supply chains and the markets of the car industry would cast doubt on the economic future of the whole industry; most of the European markets of UK agriculture and fisheries would be immediately lost and only some of them might be recovered in the long run.

In our Briefing Paper 16, we estimated that trading without a post-Brexit Free Trade Agreement with the EU might lead to a 5.5% reduction in UK manufacturing output; other estimates of the long-term effect on the whole UK economy of trading on WTO terms range between 3% and 7.5% of GDP compared with EU membership. All these estimates, however, assumed a managed and planned exit from the EU. The costs of tumbling out of the EU without a WA would be much greater. The huge costs of short-run disruption have to be added in. Short-run disruption will also have long-lived negative economic effects.

In economic terms this is not an attractive option: to be blunt, it would be an economic disaster.

Some Brexiters argue that the No Deal scenario opens the doors for Global Britain to enjoy the benefits of signing Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) with countries such as the USA and Australia. Our work suggests that even if the UK managed to sign Free Trade Agreements with all other countries in the world, the mitigating benefits would be much less than the costs of No Deal.

The next option is Mrs May’s Deal

Costing this option is harder because the WA is only the exit treaty and the PD which sketches the long-term EU-UK relationship is necessarily vague. There are pointers to the long-term but they are only pointers. The WA agreement provides a solution to the Irish border problem partly through a “temporary” customs arrangement. Since that arrangement can come to an end only when a different and, as yet, unknown solution to the border problem is found, it is wise to assume that the reality will be very close to a long-term customs union between the UK and the EU. There will also have to be regulatory alignment in goods between Northern Ireland and the EU, which will mean, in practice, regulatory alignment in goods between the whole UK and the EU. No one has yet modelled the economic consequences of this particular package of UK-EU arrangements in which there would be no tariffs and no need for customs inspections at the borders, but UK goods and services would face some regulatory costs in accessing the EU market. In our earlier modelling, we estimated that  being out of the Single Market and the Customs Union might lead to a fall in UK manufacturing output of 4%, but the fact that Mrs May’s Deal keeps the UK in the Customs Union for an indefinite time could reduce this cost to something like 2% of manufacturing output.

If one supposed that Mrs May’s Deal lies somewhere between the hard and soft Brexit options modelled in other studies, a long-term reduction in UK GDP in the area of 1-2% might be a reasonable estimate. However, services account for half of UK trade and 80% of GDP and it is very hard to make an estimate of the effect on the services sector of the UK’s exit from the Single Market. The literature can provide estimates of border costs and of the non-tariff equivalent of regulatory costs on goods; services regulation does not happen at the border and takes a wide variety of forms, not easily summarised in a tariff equivalent. It is reasonable to estimate that Mrs May’s Deal has significant economic costs which will, however, be considerably less than the costs of No Deal.

Mrs May’s Deal does not deliver the main prizes sought by the Brexiters: there’s little freedom to “strike new trade deals” around the world; limited freedom from EU regulation; little scope for an independent agricultural policy; and it comes at a significant economic cost including a substantial EU exit bill. For Brexiters, this is close to Brexit in Name Only (BINO). However, the fact that the long-term outcome is so unclear may mean that different people might support it for different reasons: Liam Fox MP and Michael Gove MP might support Mrs May’s Deal in the hope that the customs arrangement really will be temporary so that the new trade deals and the independent agricultural policy are only postponed; MPs representing constituencies where jobs depend on trade with the EU might support Mrs May’s Deal in the opposite hope that it creates a permanent Customs Union; others may support it just to ensure that the UK crosses the Brexit line without a ‘People’s Vote’.

Image courtesy of Tiocfaidh ár lá 1916 (Flickr)

This points to a wider problem with Mrs May’s Deal: it creates the prospect of a prolonged period of uncertainty about the UK’s trade arrangements. March 2019 will not be the end of the story. The WA provides for a standstill transition until December 2020 (or even longer) during which nothing much changes in the economic relationship between the EU and the UK. By the end of 2020, only the bare bones of a UK-EU FTA could be agreed, and only if it includes a solution to the Irish border issue. The UK will almost inevitably commit to remaining close to EU regulation in both goods and services and in areas such as environmental regulation and state aid. There is also a reasonable prospect that in both goods and services the UK will face relatively low EU regulatory barriers as well as zero tariffs past January 2020. However, the UK will still be in a customs union and we’ll be a long way from an agreement in agriculture that would allow the UK to diverge significantly from the Common Agricultural Policy.

Many members of the UK Government would happily have signed up to a hard Brexit which would be disastrous for much of UK manufacturing. The Irish border problem has forced at least some of them, reluctantly, to sign up to Mrs May’s Deal. They will be campaigning in the coming years for an early exit from the customs arrangement, and potential foreign investors in the UK now know that their interests do not rank high in the priorities of many ministers. A climate of uncertainty is uninviting to firms contemplating making long-term investment in the UK economy. In Briefing Paper 23, Ilona Serwicka and Nicolo Tamberi show that following the Brexit vote, inward investment in greenfield projects has already been 16-20 per cent lower than it would have been if the UK had voted to remain a member of the EU. The uncertainties of Mrs May’s Deal are likely to exacerbate and prolong the decline in investment.

Parliament has other options. It could decide to remain in the Single Market as well as the Customs Union.

The non-EU countries in the European Economic Area (EEA) are not in a Customs Union (CU) with the EU, indeed their membership of the European Free Trade Association prevents this. But if the UK Parliament decided to go for an EEA+CU option, it’s very likely that the 27 EU members and the 3 EFTA members of the EEA could agree to the necessary changes to the EEA and EFTA treaties. The WA and the PD would need to be amended too. Then the transition period after March 2019 really would be an implementation period for an EEA+CU arrangement to be completed before the end of 2020.

The economic costs of this option would be very low compared with the status quo of EU membership. The UK, as a member state of the EU, successfully litigated in the Court of Justice (CJEU) against the attempt by the European Central Bank (ECB) to move the lucrative trade in euro-denominated securities out of London and into the Eurozone: there would now be no barrier to the ECB doing what it has long wanted. More generally, as a non-EU member of the EEA, the UK would have a much-reduced voice in the making of EU rules. In both goods and services, UK producers might face regulations that took less account of their interests than if the UK had continued as a member of the EU. These costs are hard to quantify, but it’s reasonable to predict that they will be relatively small.

Brexit would be delivered at a lower cost, with a new and settled UK-EU relationship in place by December 2020. We’d all benefit from certainty. But the Brexiters object that this really would be BINO. The UK would be even more closely tied to the EU than in Mrs May’s Deal. We’d be out of the direct jurisdiction of the CJEU, but still closely tied to the jurisprudence of the CJEU through the EFTA court.  Membership of the EEA also means continued freedom of movement of workers between the UK and other EEA members. This too is an economic plus – the clear economic evidence is that freedom of movement makes UK workers and the UK economy better off. And it’s worth noting recent evidence that a majority of UK citizens are content to have freedom of movement continue.

The last option is for the UK to abandon Brexit and remain in the EU.

There may be formidable political problems and timing problems if Parliament were to choose this option, not least because of the timetable for the 2019 elections to the European Parliament. But the economics is simple – staying in the EU is the least costly option. Mrs May this week noted that it is on the table.

These choices are political, not economic. Economists can just point out that the choice is not between two options, No Deal with its disastrous costs and Mrs May’s Deal whose costs are high; it’s a choice between four options of which the last two, remaining in the Single Market and Customs Union or abandoning Brexit, have low and zero cost. That’s as far as economic analysis takes us. Parliament: the next move is yours.

 

Disclaimer:

The opinions expressed in this blog are those of the author alone and do not necessarily represent the opinions of the University of Sussex or UK Trade Policy Observatory.

Republishing guidelines:

The UK Trade Policy Observatory believes in the free flow of information and encourages readers to cite our materials, providing due acknowledgement. For online use, this should be a link to the original resource on our website. We do not publish under a Creative Commons license. This means you CANNOT republish our articles online or in print for free.